« CFPB "Abusive" Rulemaking? | Main | For-profit college chain files (for receivership) »

CLO Yawn

posted by Adam Levitin

There's a big story in the NY Times about how the financial structures being used to finance many corporate loans—so-called Collateralized Loan Obligations or CLOs—look very similar to those used to finance mortgages during the housing bubble.  Yup.  That's true. CLOs are a securitization structure, like MBS.  (If you want to know more gory details, see here.)  But that's really where the similarities end.  While the financing transactions are similar, the asset class being securitized is fundamentally different in terms of the risk it presents, and that's what matters.  The financing channel might be more vulnerable to underpricing than other financing channels because of opacity and complexity, but is the underlying asset class that matters in terms of societal impact.  This is for (at least) four reasons. 

First, corporate debt values are not correlated with each other in the way housing values are. Underpriced housing financing results in an asset price bubble because of the serially and geographically correlated nature of housing prices. When housing finance is underpriced, borrowers can bid up home prices. That in turn increases the ability of other borrowers to get credit against other properties because loan amounts are based on property valuations, and valuations are based on comparable properties.  This mechanism also works in reverse, when housing prices fall, and gets exacerbated because when a borrower defaults, the borrower usually ceases to care for the property, which pushes down the value of nearby properties.

There's no equivalent mechanism with corporate borrowing. If Firm X defaults on its loan, it doesn't affect the value of a loan to Firm Y or of Firm Y itself, any more than your default on an auto loan affects the value of my auto loan or my car.  Housing is just different.  Thus, bad loans to one company don't have the same spillover effects as bad residential mortgage loans. 

There could still be spillover effects from corporate defaults if lots of financial institutions take huge losses and are decapitalized and can't lend, but that would take a lot of losses happening at the same time, and post-Dodd-Frank there is better (and to some degree more) capital in the financial system. Doesn't mean that losses won't sting, but the system is less fragile.

Bad mortgages metastasized into a financial crisis in 2008 not just through their financialization through securitization, but also because MBS were being widely used as repo collateral, and their value as a class became uncertain.  I don't have a sense of how widely CLOs are being used as repo collateral, but there are a lot less of them than private-label MBS, so I suspect the issue is less here.  More importantly, the problem in the fall of 2008 wasn't really realized losses--only a tenth of ultimate losses on mortgages had been realized by then.  It was the uncertainty of the extent of future losses.  Those should be more predictable on CLOs.  There are many fewer underlying borrower companies, and the lack of correlation on defaults and recoveries among the underlying loans makes it easier to predict losses, even with complicated cashflow waterfalls.

Second, housing is of macroeconomic importance in a way that corporate debt is not. Part of it is the size of the market--the $12.0 trillion residential mortgage market is much bigger than the corporate debt market ($8.6 trillion total). [As an aside, this raises the question of why corporate finance is a standard law school offering, but not housing finance...]

But it's not just about size. Home equity is the major asset for most households, whereas household exposure to corporate debt markets is limited and indirect. Most households have limited investments (if any) in securities, and most of those are in equities or government debt, not corporate debt. This matters because it means that we are unlikely to see a wealth effect recession from problems in the corporate debt market.  Mian and Sufi's work has shown that the impairment of household balance sheets played a critical role in the Great Recession--as household's saw their wealth diminish, they pared back on spending. That's not a mechanism that's going to happen with corporate debt. 

Third, there's a much better market clearing mechanism for corporate debt than for mortgages:  bankruptcy.  Corporate debt obligations get cleared in bankruptcy.  If there's a discrepancy between collateral value and debt amount for corporate debt, bankruptcy's got a ready solution, namely stripping down the secured claim to the value of the collateral. But thanks to Nobelman and Caulkett, that's not possible for home mortgage debt.  Instead, the clearing mechanism for housing is foreclosure, which is a woefully inefficient process that overcorrects.  Bankruptcy does a reasonably good job of market clearing. 

Fourth, there's also the possibility of private workouts—the loan sizes in CLOs make it worth the time for CLO managers to take the time to negotiate workouts, to the extent the CLO structure allows it.  (Limitations on changes of CLO payment terms--a sort of Trust Indenture Act § 316(b) issue, but done through contractual terms—may be an issue here, however.)  The problems that existed (and exist) with residential mortgage loan servicing simply don't have an analog with CLO restructurings of underlying loans. 

To the extent I've got a systemic concern about CLOs, it is about the risk of sponsor-support resulting in insured deposits being used to bail out CLOs.  This is something that regulators will have to police--CLOs that are getting support from their sponsors should be getting it on arm's-length terms.  But this is about policing regulatory borders, not about a fundamental problem threatening the system.

All of this is to say that there might be elevated defaults, even a bloodbath in corporate loans. But the systemic consequences will be much milder than 2008. The system should be able to handle things, and if bad investments result in investors taking losses, well, isn't that how the game is supposed to work?  As long as we don't see systemic spillovers, let the losses fall where they will.

Comments

Financialization massively increases fraud risk. When loan originators lack “skin in the game” they’ll lie about the quality of collateral and creditworthiness of the borrower or they’ll go out of business (sooner rather than later.) MBS fraud requires control of appraisals and repayment ability verifications. CLO fraud is a walk in the park by comparison – accounting statements and cashflow/income forecasts are far easier to control. It’s even easier to game the creditworthiness of financial firms seeking loans.

Just as with housing appraisals, bond ratings for companies in similar sectors are correlated. Defaults and bond downgrades for one will hurt ratings of their suppliers and often other players in the sector. As we saw during the S&L and financial crises, this is especially true in the financial sector. While real estate short sales will have very localized impact on collateral value, corporate loan defaults undermine the confidence in the procedures that valued the collateral (enough real estate defaults can do the same.)

Before CLOs, lenders were free to use different criteria for corporate lending. Financialization forces these procedures to be highly correlated if not the same – this required standardization becomes a key source of contagion risk. Ultimately, as in the financial crisis, entire markets for commercial paper and financialized products fail because trust evaporates. Without massive government backstops during the financial crisis, many more companies would have failed along with the CLOs that depended on their survival.

On point 2 of the original post, retirement assets and secure employment are at least as important as real estate equity for most folks. To the extent CLOs are making it easier for companies to buyback stock with debt and place companies in financial distress, retirement assets and jobs are being placed at risk for the benefit of management.

You might be right about bankruptcy leading to more effective asset write-downs in corporate defaults than with home loans. However, incentivizing private equity and other owners to asset-strip and bankrupt companies for short-term gains while dumping liabilities on society isn’t useful. We don’t need to permit it and certainly shouldn’t be encouraging it with CLOs.

On point 4 of the original post, what incentivizes CLO managers to provide workouts that benefit investors? During the financial crisis these folks took advantage of their positions and informational advantages to feather their own nests at investor expense. Why can’t that happen again?

Are corporate loans really less risky than real estate? Should we allow originators to package and sell CLOs without absorbing any financial risk? Will honest lenders successfully compete against fraudulent originators? Will pensioners, the insured and the rest of the “dumb money” buy side avoid getting fleeced again on lightly regulated CLOs? Will the financial system function smoothly if the CLO market becomes illiquid? I’m not convinced.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Contributors

Current Guests

Follow Us On Twitter

Like Us on Facebook

  • Like Us on Facebook

    By "Liking" us on Facebook, you will receive excerpts of our posts in your Facebook news feed. (If you change your mind, you can undo it later.) Note that this is different than "Liking" our Facebook page, although a "Like" in either place will get you Credit Slips post on your Facebook news feed.

Categories

Bankr-L

  • As a public service, the University of Illinois College of Law operates Bankr-L, an e-mail list on which bankruptcy professionals can exchange information. Bankr-L is administered by one of the Credit Slips bloggers, Professor Robert M. Lawless of the University of Illinois. Although Bankr-L is a free service, membership is limited only to persons with a professional connection to the bankruptcy field (e.g., lawyer, accountant, academic, judge). To request a subscription on Bankr-L, click here to visit the page for the list and then click on the link for "Subscribe." After completing the information there, please also send an e-mail to Professor Lawless ([email protected]) with a short description of your professional connection to bankruptcy. A link to a URL with a professional bio or other identifying information would be great.

OTHER STUFF