Thoughts on Nortel (from Bob Rasmussen)
The following post comes to us from Professor Rasmussen at USC:
Nortel Bankruptcy Sets a Dangerous Precedent For the Future of Lending
Lenders are no fools. They care deeply about the promises they receive in return for the money they hand over to the borrower. And if a 2015 ruling in the long-running Nortel Networks bankruptcy case is allowed to stand, it could lead to more restrictive lending to borrowers in the future.
For decades, our commercial law has allowed enterprises to divvy up promises as they see fit. Companies often conduct business through multiple, related entities. This allows lenders to extend credit knowing they’ll receive repayment for their loans from particularly asset-rich subsidiaries, that are not on the hook for all of the debts of the business. This adroit use of the corporate structure allows borrowers to get funds at a lower cost and, in the extreme, can mean securing a loan or not — which can be the difference in a business being able to operate.
Until recently, a lender taking a promise from a subsidiary of a business could rest assured that its only other competition to the subsidiary’s assets would be the other creditors. A recent case, however, threatens to overturn this accepted wisdom and bring uncertainty to financing of large enterprises.
In early 2009, after years of declining fortunes, Nortel’s various operating units sought bankruptcy protection. In years past, bankruptcy was a place where a debtor sought to reorganize its affairs and return to the marketplace. Not so much today. Today, bankruptcy has become the realm of sales. Usually when a major business files for bankruptcy, it will see the bulk of its operations sold off to the highest bidder.
This is what happened in Nortel’s case. Its various business operations were sold as operating units. Nortel’s prize asset – its hoard of intellectual property – sold at auction to a group of some of the world’s leading technology companies for $4.5 billion. Two and a half years after filing for bankruptcy, all of Nortel’s assets had been converted to cash. The final step was to divide the cash – well more than $6 billion – among the various creditors.
This was no ministerial task. There were vigorous disputes over who owned the assets that had been sold. For physical assets, it was clear which entity owned them prior to sale. The intellectual property was another matter. The Canadian creditors claimed the Canadian parent, which held legal title to all of Nortel’s intellectual property prior to the sales, owned it. The UK and European creditors claimed the company as a whole had created the assets, and thus the entire company owned them. The United States creditors pointed out that the various subsidiaries in each country had been granted an exclusive license to use, sell and market the intellectual property in that country. Accordingly, they asserted that each unit owned the right to sell, use and market the intellectual property in that country.
In 2015, six years after the company filed for bankruptcy, a pair of U.S. and Canadian bankruptcy judges jointly sided with the Americans on this score. After parsing through the various agreements among the Nortel entities as well as intellectual property law, the court ruled that the intellectual property was in effect owned by the appropriate subsidiary in each country.
Despite this, the court then curiously departed from settled law and sound principles by issuing a ruling that parceled out the funds based on how much the various entities owed their creditors. In essence, the court would add up what the U.S. creditors were owed, what the Canadian creditors were owed, and what the U.K. creditors were owed, and then divvy up the proceeds accordingly. If one group had, for example 40% of the claims against it, that group would get 40% of the pooled funds.
Rather than allocating the assets by how much each side owned, as is typical in these cases, they would be divided by how much each side owed. This disregard for the ownership interests in the assets has little to commend it. But this is a game that can only be played once.
There is little about Nortel that is unique. It was a multinational enterprise. While it operated as a whole, it was careful to respect corporate form. Indeed, it was because of the fact that Nortel kept its subsidiaries separate that those buying the bonds of the U.S. company were content to rely on its credit alone.
Such reliance on corporate structure is commonly respected. In Owens Corning, the lender lent money to one part of the Owens Corning enterprise, and took guarantees from the rest. These subsidiaries did not have many claims against them, and thus, like the lender here, the lenders in Owens Corning knew they would have first claim on the subsidiary’s assets, above those who lent to other members of the corporate group. In rejecting an attempt to disregard the borrower’s corporate structure, the court in that case noted, “This kind of lending occurs every business day.”
The reason for the court’s reluctance to undo carefully structured transactions was clear. Our commercial law system allows businesses to have whatever corporate structure they see fit. With that structure in place, they can seek credit by whatever basket of promises will allow them access to funds at the lowest possible costs. Those lending the money protect themselves via contract. They know which parts of the corporate structure they can turn to for repayment, and they know they will not be competing against creditors of other related entities for a limited pile of funds.
The Nortel bankruptcy court was understandably frustrated by some of the arguments offered by several of the parties and by what it viewed as not wholly credible evidence on some valuation issues. That said, these deficiencies do not support the jettisoning of sound commercial practice.
Each side of Nortel’s global units will head back to the courtroom on April 5 to deliver oral appeals arguments. Should the allocation method offered by the Nortel ruling withstand an appeal, lenders run the risk of thinking they can no longer rely on corporate structures when extending monies. Having relied and lost, they will be less likely to rely in the future.
Material in this post originally appeared at Law306 (subscription required).
I would like to see the actual ruling so I could see what the court considers its justification to be.
Posted by: Knute Rife | April 21, 2016 at 07:00 PM
Why is it that the subsidiary lenders get to insist on the corporate form's strict recognition in dividing the assets yet clamor for a collective approach ignoring that form when selling those same assets? And the welfare effects are ambiguous at best, aren't they? For every purportedly disappointed lender who did worse off under this outcome, weren't there an equal and opposite number who did better off? So unless one considers the "uncertainty costs" non-trivial and lemons-inducing, what's the problem? Certainly the upside is windfall prevention when int'l conglomerates park their IP assets in certain specific subs for compliance purposes. The Dean Emeritus doth protest too much, methinks.
Posted by: John Pottow | April 22, 2016 at 11:56 PM
Thank you for posting this Bob. It is a strange ruling.
I want to object to one statement that you made, specifically that "usually when a major business files for bankruptcy, it will see the bulk of its operations sold off to the highest bidder." Would that that were the case. My company helps investors find investment opportunities in bankruptcy. Most of the opportunities occur in small to middle market companies rather than large enterprises.
Since the 2005 changes to the bankruptcy laws, larger bankruptcies are more likely to come in a "pre-packaged" agreements to hand over the keys to the lenders. Bankruptcy court is used only to anoint the transfer and provide a mechanism for new priming loans (DIP loans). Plans may include the sale of some assets (like in Swift Energy) but it is far from a wholesale auctioning of everything.
Posted by: John | April 23, 2016 at 05:56 PM
Rasmussen seems to have misunderstood the courts problem. It was valuation - when the Nortel patents were sold by the patent owning company, the sale was supported by a bunch of releases from the other Nortel subs. So getting rid of licenses, restrictions, potential legal claims on the patents, etc as otherwise the patents wouldn't be saleable. These various release weren't valued at the time- so the courts were left with the problem of how to split up the sale proceeds. None of the parties gave (in the opinion of the courts) a valid way to assign a value to the individual IP assets owned by each company, so they figured out one themselves.
Not a pretty solution, but at some point, money needs to go to the creditors instead of being burnt on legal fees. More than 1B spent already.
Posted by: San | April 24, 2016 at 11:58 PM
I'm assuming the IP sales San is referring to were 363 sales. If so, why weren't the proceeds divided as part of the approval order? I had a hearing last week in a Chapter 13 case with a 100% plan, and debtors wanted approval for the sale of their house, which would cash out the plan and end the case. Neither the court nor the Chapter 13 trustee would budge until I could provide a closing statement showing where the proceeds were going. If that wasn't done here (and apparently it wasn't), then somebody seriously dropped the ball. Or is this yet another nicety that applies only to us mortals but that the multi-giga-sized Chapter 11 gods on Olympus don't have to bother with?
Posted by: Knute Rife | April 26, 2016 at 06:23 PM
On the lighter side, that tangled bankruptc y proceeding also featured Google’s bid of pi for Nortel Networks’ wireless patent portfolio. Specifically, Google big $3.14159 billion. The great thing about bidding pi is that if another team that loves irrational-numeric constants bids e, then pi wins.
Posted by: Christopher Faille | April 29, 2016 at 07:31 AM
Just a quick response to my friend John Pottow. Sure, there is a benefit in the collective proceeding here -- it allowed a sale that would have been hard if not impossible to pull off outside of bankruptcy. Yet that is true of bankruptcy outcomes generally, no? We could live in a world where once you are in bankruptcy, creditors lose their pre-bankruptcy entitlements on the grounds that it is the forum that is creating value. Just as the collective forum provides value here, it provides value when there is a reorganization that you could not have pulled off outside of bankruptcy. We could say, well, secured creditors, there was benefit from the collective forum, so we will just ignore your state law priority and allocate the proceeds pro rata among all creditors. Winners and losers would, in some sense, balance off. Such a world may or may not be sensible, but I don't think it is our world. We by and large follow entitlements created by non-bankruptcy law, and the court here went astray by not doing so.
Posted by: Bob Rasmussen | April 29, 2016 at 05:52 PM
Knute
The sale wasn't a 363 sale as the main patent holder was Canadian, so subject to Canadian law with other subsidiaries being subject to US and European (think mostly British) insolvency rules. This is likely one of those "big companies" only rulings as who else would have such a value or volume of IP intertwined with so many related companies and subject to residual legal claims that is worth fighting in multiple courts for 5 years.
As far as anyone dropping the ball, I'm not sure I'd agree. The core assets (free and clear title to the patents) are wasting by nature. They are worth less every month. So the bankruptcy estates (collectively) were better off selling right away and figuring out values later. The patents were worth $4.5B in 2011. What would they be worth in 2016? Significantly less since patents age. From a bankruptcy policy standpoint, the 2011 sale maximized the cash available to the creditors, even though it was unclear which estates (and therefore which creditors) were owed what.
Posted by: SAN | May 18, 2016 at 11:52 AM