« Who Owns the MBS Claims? AIG or the Fed? | Main | Stripping Down Bankruptcy Jargon »

QM Impact on the Mortgage Market

posted by Adam Levitin

The American Banker has a story (paywalled) about the impact of the QM rule on subprime lending. Subprime loans are unlikely to qualify for the full QM safe harbor because they are typically priced at more than 150 bps above prime. This means that subprime borrowers now have a possible foreclosure defense if they can show that the lender failed to properly account for their ability to repay. The result is to increase the risk lenders incur with subprime loans. But how much does this matter?

The American Banker story contains an estimate that only 5% of today's mortgage volume would fall outside of QM. Today, however, is an ultra conservative mortgage market. We can get a rough sense of what the impact of QM would have been in the past by looking at the market share of subprime and Alt-A loans.  

The CFPB's rulemaking has an estimate for the 1997-2003 period roughly 70% of originations would have been QM, with 22% non-QM and 8% consisting of loans that can no longer legally be made.  (The CFPB's rulemaking also estimates a very minimal impact on mortgage pricing, p.582 and following in the rulemaking.)

My own back-of-the-envelope estimate roughly in line with that.  Let's say that all of subprime originations and Alt-A originations would not have qualified for QM.  Some prime loans wouldn't either, but they aren't easily broken out of the data. Below is a chart showing the market share of subprime and of subprime and Alt-A originations by dollar amount. If my estimate is correct, then this is approximately the share of mortgages that would have been covered by QM in the past (assuming that nothing else had changed). Of course, had QM existed, it's possible a lot would have been different, and if it really will chill non-QM originations, it suggests we might well have avoided the housing bubble.

Subprime & Alt-A

A few more comments on the QM rulemaking:

  1. Some commentators have taken the mortgage industry's sigh of relief over the QM rulemaking as a sign that it is a weak or bad rulemaking. I think that's poorly considered. I haven't seen any consumer groups expressing disappointment. It might not be exactly what every consumer group hoped for, but a win is a win. The mortgage industry's relief is explained by two factors. First, QM isn't going to have much effect on current business because the mortgage industry isn't doing much in the way of subprime anymore. And that's fine. QM is meant to preclude the type of poorly underwritten loans made during the housing bubble, not create a right to litigate underwriting of every mortgage loan. And second, industry reactions are in part determined by expectations. The financial services industry beat itself into a frenzy between 2009 and present worrying about the CFPB as national credit commissar. I think many in the industry started to believe their own rhetoric. Perhaps the QM rulemaking will encourage some more realistic appraisals of the agency by the financial services industry.
  2. Some commentators have been baffled by the lack of down payment or FICO requirements in QM. I'm not sure why. Down payments don't show ability to make monthly payments. They're relevant from a creditor perspective in terms of ensuring borrower skin-in-the-game, but they don't seem to have much to do with ability to repay. That's why downpayments are likely going to be part of the interagency Qualified Residential Mortgage (QRM) investor protection rulemaking, but aren't in QM. And mandating FICO scores are just kind of silly for ability to repay. Would QM really require a 620 or 660 FICO? What does FICO add that income and asset verification and back-end DTI doesn't?
  3. My original QM post (now corrected) missed the sunset provision regarding the GSEs. This is important. At the sooner of 2021 or the end of conservatorship, GSE purchase eligibility ceases to satisfy parts of the QM definition. In other words, GSE underwriting is only being used as a partial proxy for ability to repay while the GSEs are under tight federal control.
  4. Finally, I missed two more behavioral economics tidbits in the rulemaking, both on page 557. This is all I can find in 804 pages.

"Consumers may underestimate the true costs of homeownership or be overly optimistic about their own future (or even current) financial condition."

"Further, consumers may not understand or may underestimate the costs they will incur in the event of default, such as the loss of the borrower’s own home, costs of relocation, and the borrower’s loss of future credit, employment and other opportunities for which credit reports or credit scores weigh in the decision."

I'm not sure how much behavioral economics is necessary to get to these insights, but there it is. So much for the behavioral bogeyman.

Comments

One comment and one (slightly off topic) question.

In your comments on FICO scores, using FICO scores seems to have the same risk as basing bank capital requirements on bond credit ratings -- there will be an incentive to fiddle with FICO scores to fit whatever becomes a QM.

Also, a question relating to the whole mortgage mess a few years ago. I've noticed that those blaming the government and GSEs for the crisis equate "subprime" or "Alt-A" mortgage with low income mortgages. The other side blames Wall Street greed (or some variant).

While there is a lot of data showing the large percentage of subprime mortgages during this period, I haven't found data giving the percentage of subprime mortgages broken out by the size of the mortgage (or by which qualify for CRA credit). While mortgage size doesn't correlate directly to income, I would assume subprime / Alt-A mortgages for million dollar houses are probably not being written to meet CRA requirements.

Does anybody know where I can find data breaking out mortgage quality / type by size?

It should also be noted that the CFPB has proposed changing the definition of finance charge to be more inclusive. Fees such as title insurance, appraisal, notary fees, survey fees, flood, and others will be considered a finance charge when the integrated mortgage disclosure rule goes into affect. This will increase the APR on all loans which will of course increase the APOR, so it is difficult to know what effect this will have on the number of high priced mortgage loans. I imagine these fees will impact the APR of smaller loans more because these fees increase only marginally with the size of the loan.

Would it kill ya to say what "QM" is for those who don't immediately know?

The jargon on this website makes it more opaque than it needs to be.

"QM" = Qualified Mortgage.

I wonder how extensive the CFPB's ability to change the definition of "finance charge" is. Will turning these into "interest" mean that these charges are now tax deductible? If not, we could end up with two definitions of a finance charge, one for tax purposes, one for qualified mortgages. I'm not sure that would be a good idea.

Though I've noticed that many tax / business laws lately should be subtitled "the no accountant / lawyer left behind act". :-)

I am curious about the impact of the QM regulation on the Holder in Due Course doctrine.

Regardless of whether it provides a "safe harbor" or not, doesn't the QM regulation make the promise to pay in a promissory note conditional on the debtor's ability to re-pay? While the creditor may be able to establish that the safe-harbor rules were met in court, the obligation is conditional on the creditor doing so.

Whether or not an assignee of a note is a Holder in Due Course is binary. An assignee can't get HDC status by proving a condition to pay has been met. If a condition exists, the promise to pay is not "unconditional" which is what is required for HDC status.

Pretty much the entire structure of the mortgage secondary market is based on assignees of notes and mortgages having HDC status - including reps and warranties on transfer agreements. Doesn't QM force an entire re-thinking of secondary market economics - or at least documentation?

More importantly, doesn't the QM regulation now give the borrower his day in court for the first time in the mortgage world to assert defenses against the assignee(s)of the borrower's note? Until now, the assignee could just assert HDC status. Granted, the assignees can show up in court to prove the safe harbor was met but this still would appear to significantly change the economics and relative bargaining power of the parties.

Tim,

I am not sure how a new defense would change things. There are already defenses to enforcement of a note by a Holder in Due Course. Fraud, duress, etc. I do not think that an additional defense makes the promise to pay "conditional" in that sense.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Contributors

Current Guests

Follow Us On Twitter

Like Us on Facebook

  • Like Us on Facebook

    By "Liking" us on Facebook, you will receive excerpts of our posts in your Facebook news feed. (If you change your mind, you can undo it later.) Note that this is different than "Liking" our Facebook page, although a "Like" in either place will get you Credit Slips post on your Facebook news feed.

Categories

Bankr-L

  • As a public service, the University of Illinois College of Law operates Bankr-L, an e-mail list on which bankruptcy professionals can exchange information. Bankr-L is administered by one of the Credit Slips bloggers, Professor Robert M. Lawless of the University of Illinois. Although Bankr-L is a free service, membership is limited only to persons with a professional connection to the bankruptcy field (e.g., lawyer, accountant, academic, judge). To request a subscription on Bankr-L, click here to visit the page for the list and then click on the link for "Subscribe." After completing the information there, please also send an e-mail to Professor Lawless ([email protected]) with a short description of your professional connection to bankruptcy. A link to a URL with a professional bio or other identifying information would be great.

OTHER STUFF