« Promoting Investment in Education through Income-Contingent Lending | Main | Transforming the Way We Finance Higher Education »

Precedents for Income-Contingent Lending, at Home and Abroad

posted by David Moss

Earlier this week, I suggested that we consider a new system of income-contingent lending (ICL) to ensure that every American can cover the cost of higher education.  Surprisingly, the notion of income-contingent lending, now viewed as a liberal idea, was originally conceived by a well-known conservative economist. Milton Friedman suggested a federal ICL-style program to help finance professional education as early as 1945, and he extended the proposal ten years later to cover virtually all higher education.

In Friedman’s view, the market system on its own produced “underinvestment in human capital” as a result of “an imperfection in the capital market.” Private lending for investment in human capital (education) was far riskier than for investment in physical capital (plant and equipment) because the former could not be collateralized – i.e., because slavery was prohibited. The government, however, could effectively collateralize human capital given its power to tax future earnings. As a result, a federal ICL program would, in Friedman’s words, “make capital more widely available [to students] and would thereby do much to make equality of opportunity a reality, to diminish inequalities of income and wealth, and to promote the full use of our human resources.”[1]

The economist (and Kennedy advisor) James Tobin not only supported the idea of income-contingent lending, he actually helped put such a system in place at Yale University in the early 1970s. Yale’s Tuition Postponement Option obligated borrowers to pay 0.4% of their adjusted gross income, for up to 35 years (or until their cohort had repaid its debt in full), on each $1000 of tuition postponed (borrowed). The repayment schedule included both a minimum ($29 per $1000 borrowed) and a maximum (150% of principal, scaled up year by year according to a variable interest rate). The program was ultimately terminated in 1978, in large part because of problems with collection and unexpectedly high payments required of high-income graduates. Still, the program offers important clues about how best to structure a federal ICL program. It also helped many students from low-income families afford a Yale education, including one particular Yale law student named Bill Clinton.

In fact, it was probably no coincidence that as President,Clinton initially favored an income-contingent approach in reforming the nation’s system of financial aid. Yet his ICL proposal faced strong opposition from private lenders. In the end, the watered-down version of an ICL plan that President Clinton signed into law in 1993 was so weak that it had barely any effect on student borrowing and has gone largely unnoticed.

The ICL idea was employed with considerably greater success – and fanfare – abroad. Beginning in the late 1980s, a number of countries adopted ICL programs to help cover university tuition, including Australia (1989), New Zealand (1992), and the United Kingdom (1997).[2] Although many of these programs appear to be working well, it is doubtful that any would be directly transferable to the United States, given substantial differences in country context. Most of the foreign programs, for example, exhibit only a weak market orientation – in most cases charging no interest on loans. The sums involved are also much smaller than they would be here, since the U.S. is effectively in a league of its own with respect to tuition levels. Still, the spread of income-contingent lending overseas is important, reflecting the broad appeal of the idea and providing a solid empirical basis for determining the best ways to structure a program here at home.


[1] In fact, Friedman’s proposal went further than the one I outlined in my last post, since Friedman's plan would have required students to repay to the federal government a fixed percentage of their future income indefinitely, rather than simply to repay their own individual loans. He characterized this as an equity arrangement (instead of debt), whereby the government would “’buy’ a share in an individual’s earning prospects.” To simplify administration, he recommended that “the appropriate unit of government to make funds available is the Federal government….” See Milton Friedman, “The Role of Government in Education,” in Economics and the Public Interest, ed. Robert A. Solo (New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press, 1955).

[2] This paragraph draws on Yael Shavit, “Promoting Equal Access to Higher Education: the Past and Future of Income Contingent Loans,” unpublished draft, January 2007. While program details vary from country to country, Australia’s program is reasonably typical: students can borrow up to the cost of tuition and, after graduation, pay 4-8 percent of their income each year until the principal (adjusted for inflation) is fully repaid. No payment is required in any year in which the borrower’s income falls below a threshold level, which currently stands at about AU$38,000 (approximately US$30,000).

Comments

The comments to this entry are closed.

Contributors

Current Guests

Follow Us On Twitter

Like Us on Facebook

  • Like Us on Facebook

    By "Liking" us on Facebook, you will receive excerpts of our posts in your Facebook news feed. (If you change your mind, you can undo it later.) Note that this is different than "Liking" our Facebook page, although a "Like" in either place will get you Credit Slips post on your Facebook news feed.

Categories

Bankr-L

  • As a public service, the University of Illinois College of Law operates Bankr-L, an e-mail list on which bankruptcy professionals can exchange information. Bankr-L is administered by one of the Credit Slips bloggers, Professor Robert M. Lawless of the University of Illinois. Although Bankr-L is a free service, membership is limited only to persons with a professional connection to the bankruptcy field (e.g., lawyer, accountant, academic, judge). To request a subscription on Bankr-L, click here to visit the page for the list and then click on the link for "Subscribe." After completing the information there, please also send an e-mail to Professor Lawless ([email protected]) with a short description of your professional connection to bankruptcy. A link to a URL with a professional bio or other identifying information would be great.

OTHER STUFF